When they did that financial oppression playbook of, you know, hold rates, you know, basically let inflation run hot compared to interest rates. You know, eventually people want out. There's that IMF paper by Reinhardt, Carmen Reinhardt, I think she phrased it like you need a captive audience, right? If you're going to inflate the data way, you got to keep people in the debt. And if your money is going to lose value, how do you keep people in the money?
Welcome to the Amestus Podcast. I'm your host, Nick Broderson and your listener. We are in good company. With us, we have the one and only, Lynn Alden. Welcome back to the show, Lynn. Thanks for having me back. Happy to be here.
So, Lynn, it's always great having you here on the show. And I want to start this interview by discussing the energy market. And I'll be referencing your wonderful blog post. I have you to write here, Energy, the Area Under the Curve, for the first part of the episode. So in here, you're claiming that the industry is acting more rational than before. And you also refer to the USL producers, which, unlike in the past, are more disciplined now and they only produce profitable oil and gas. And I found this very interesting, this statement, because we think and perhaps understand that a tech company, think about Facebook or Google, like, they might be horrible to utilize networking effects and achieve super normal profits. And they can be okay with being unprofitable for some time as they're getting there. I wrote the situation seems perhaps not to be applicable to all the gas producers. So could you please paint some color around why top line growth was more important than profits in the prior decade for USL producers?
Yeah, it's a good comparison. I would say even in the tech space, that can get over its keys, right? So the idea of tech is that, you know, you can start out on profitable, but because you can scale exponentially, ideally, your revenues will scale faster than your expenses because, you know, it doesn't, you know, if more people are using your server, right, that's pretty cost effective. And your increase of need for staff and servers is slower than your increase of revenue can generate with those servers.
And so that's the general idea of one of those, like, you know, big type of like scaling tech startups. And so, you know, they can manage five, 10 years of unprofitability as long as there's a future vision towards profitability. That's realistic.
I think actually what we've seen with a lot of these recent growth stocks is they pushed that too far. I mean, they went into an environment where, you know, you're basically selling $20 bills for $10, which of course, anybody can grow when they're doing that. If you're being so generous with your pricing and just kind of using your stock to pay employees. And so you're, you know, you're kind of saving on costs there. You're kind of just really pushing it far. It shows even tech companies, it can be irrational in terms of not having a vision towards profitability that's realistic.
And you know, with oil companies, just, you know, there was new technology, right? So there was, you know, we're not in it was combination of new technology and specifically new implementation of those technologies. So it's not like, you know, there was advancements in how to get that oil out combined with, you know, just new visualizing tools and all sorts of those newer finements that marginal difference that helps make it more profitable or at least doable combined with an era of record low interest rates.
You know, they brought interest till near zero. There's rounds of QA. And then you had a number of pension funds and other entities like that being, you want to buy up all the debt and equity that they're willing to issue. And then a lot of CO compensation is tied to how big your company is not necessarily how, you know, what your net margin is, or even what your total return is, or over say, a five year period. And so there's a lot of just problematic incentives in the sector.
And you know, the idea is it's always, it's going to keep growing. It's always going to be demand. We'll get profitable eventually. And of course, the apps that happened that a lot of these companies just had no clear vision towards profitability. They were over investing in that period of pricing. And like any, you know, commodity markets that get overextended, they got crushed pretty hard both in the aftermath of 2014. And then, you know, a second time, kind of not their fault in 2020. They kind of washed out any of the ones that kind of staggered, you know, to, you know, pass that earlier washout.
And so I think we're in a very different environment now where, you know, one is that due to ESG concerns and just bad returns, a lot of investors just don't want to, you know, just keep pouring money into that space anymore. And so those companies are forcing you more self-contained. They're saying, okay, instead of just issuing tons of shares in debt, we're going to actually focus on free cash flow generation. And then we're going to use that free cash flow to pay down debt, buyback shares, fun new growth and due dividends, right? So it's a more self-contained type of model, which is slower growing, but it's more profitable, less risky. And it generally results in less oil and gas growth. And so that's, I mean, that's a more rational price. And until the price gets high enough that more long duration projects come online or other energy solutions materialize that are, you know, taking that share.
Yeah. And I think you bring up a good point that we see so many weird things happening in the financial markets. You also mentioned comms for CEOs. Like we all react to incentives and it doesn't mean that they're aligned with shareholders or they're aligned with ESG or, you know, but we react to our own incentives one way or the other. And the old market is notoriously known for being volatile.
And it's important to understand that the boom and bust cycle, for example, you know, the oil price is partly due to the time lag that it takes to add or it could also be removing capacity to the market. You know, an oil project can be unprofitable in total costs, but can still be rational to continue due to the differences in fixed and variable cost. And I don't know, Lynn, if you could give an example of such a project and then how that impacts the cycles or the price of oil.
So I mean, shale oil, the reason people went to it in addition to new technology and new access, basically making life out of older wells is that it's fast market, right? So less upfront capital cost, but then you have quicker decline rates. And so it's, you know, you're just getting out oil and gas quicker.
Whereas if you do a gigantic offshore platform or, you know, some of those gigantic like OPEC, you know, wells, these are things that are very capital intensive upfront, but then they have these long lifetimes. Kind of the same thing for like oil sands, right? So super capital intensive upfront, but then once they're in place, they're very like low decline rates.
And so they during that environment, you know, that kind of like easy money, new tech environment, it was all about that, that rapid oil to market. And the problem is that's like the red queen syndrome. So running in place and you have to run twice as fast just to stay where you're going. They have to run twice as fast again, just to stay where you're going.
And so that's the problem with shale. And that's why you can't just go from say 5 million barrels a day to 50 million barrels a day. You know, at once you get up to 10, 13, 15, you know, whatever the number they get to right now, it's something like, you know, 12 or 13. The higher you get is just like your, your existing base is kind of dissolving under you as you're also trying to expand it. And so there's limits for how much you can push it.
And in this uncertain environment, you know, there's not a lot of incentive to go for these longer duration projects because, you know, they're being told by governments and investors, Hey, you know, we're going to phase you out in, you know, five years. And, you know, I think a lot of those targets are unrealistic, but they're being told that and they're also being told, you know, we're not going to give you tons of like financing. In fact, we're going to give a premium to these like green bonds over here instead of yours to make their costs to capital lower.
And also like, you know, we might do windfall tax. Maybe we'll see. And then so you have like the long term spreadsheet of, okay, do I don't want to put a couple of billion dollars into this like, you know, 15 year payback period project, probably not. And so right now we're kind of geared towards these quicker barrels of oil.
But I think in order to solve some of these structural energy problems, we're going to need some of these longer term projects. Right now the incentive structure doesn't incentivize that until maybe prices get crazy or there's more kind of a future clarity around, you know, maybe average pricing or that the fact that they know it'll be in demand, you know, 10 years from now.
Yeah, like the old market is just so fascinating. And you know, we might have a few decades back if we did the same interview back whenever no one knew what podcasting was, you know, we might have talked about peak oil or who knows, like, like the narrative just changes so fast whenever it comes to oil.
And I also think it's important for people to understand that right now the focus is on we shouldn't have oil and I don't want to go into the whole climate discussion necessarily. But there are plenty of oil, but it's also important to understand that the marginal cost of that oil is just very different depending on the world. And so you can put a lot online. It just takes a lot of time and it also requires different levels of price of oil before it makes sense.
And then you have the other effect, which is whenever the oil price is expensive enough, you have this other incentive that now renewables, it makes even more sense to do R&D in that field because now the opportunity cost is different than whenever, say, like a barrel oil was a 40 bucks, if it goes to $200, like we have different incentives.
So you have this volatile environment for those reasons and so many others, as you'd say. Yeah, I mean, in a prior era, if you saw oil say double, you big, okay, drill, baby, drill, let's get some more out of the ground. And now they're like, no, no, like we don't know if it's going to stay here and we don't know what the future clarity is. And so it's basically a different environment. It's a more bearish, cautious, defensive type of sentiment.
And that's long term good for price. And that's part of why commodity cycles are so boom bust is because of that delay between the price signal that tells you, bring the oil online, and then especially outside of shale, the number of years it takes you to actually bring that oil.
And so usually those bear markets are characterized by oversupply that was financed during that prior boom.
因此,通常情况下,这些熊市的特点是由先前的繁荣时期融资支持的供应过剩。
And then bull markets are characterized by the fact that that spare capacity is eventually being worked out, either due to ongoing demand growth or just gradual decline rates and lack of sufficient new investment because of bad pricing.
And when that price starts to go up, if you don't respond to it right away, even if you do, it takes years for that new supply to come online.
当价格开始上涨时,即使你立即采取行动,这新的供应也需要数年时间才能投入使用。
And in the meantime, just demand is really pressuring the existing supply.
同时,仅仅需求就对现有供应造成了巨大压力。
And that's the story of commodities in general. And that's why they tend to have these roughly 15 year cycles. I mean, it varies a little bit, but in some ways it's like clockwork because it's just the overall investment cycle of what plays out. That you could do an overlay of fiscal monetary stimulus that kind of serves as some of the transition points of economic acceleration or deceleration on top of that commodity overlay. And you get a pretty repeated cycle over the past century or so.
Yeah, and going back to the point about reacting to incentives.
是的,回到关于对激励做出反应的观点。
And to your point, you know, so sitting in Europe, I mean, don't even get mistaken all the problems we have in Europe with energy.
关于你所说的,你知道的,就坐在欧洲,我的意思是,别以为欧洲在能源方面没有问题。
And we have all the incentives that we don't want nuclear, we don't want oil, we don't want gas. We only want renewables.
我们有各种激励措施,我们不想要核能,不想要石油,也不想要天然气。我们只希望使用可再生能源。
And we previously talked here on the show why we can't just use renewables, not short term and not even medium term. There are so many things that we can always go into later that would require for that to happen. New technologies haven't been invented yet.
So we have these different quotas we need to fail. And we can say that if we import gas for another country, that we can still fill out those quotas because that quote unquote pollution happens in another place. Because even though it's natural gas, it's still fossil fuel.
So far, that project or, you know, here in Europe, like the backup has always been Russia.
到目前为止,在欧洲这个项目中,或者说备胎一直是俄罗斯。
And here we are. So this is not my plot for doing a lot of coal. That's not what I'm saying. It's just like, you have to choose and there are choices and consequences regardless of what path you're going to take.
But then it seems like the trend line of the price of oil is going higher and higher.
但是现在看起来油价的趋势线似乎不断上升。
And you point out that the US broad minus supply increased 40% since the start of 2020.
你指出,自2020年初以来,美国的广播供应减少了40%。
So you have in your research used gold as a measuring stick to normalize the price level. What do you find and what are the implications for businesses and households that has energy as an expense?
Yeah, so if you compare oil to gold historically, it's not that expensive in the grand scheme of things. It's roughly around average.
是的,历史上将石油与黄金相比较,从整体来看,它并不算太贵。大致上可以说处于平均水平。
Basically, at that point, you're ignoring the fiat denominator that everybody's seen those doom charts of like the dollar losing 99% of its value over XYZ time period, you know, things like that. So you ignore that gradually debasing denominator and you just compare two commodities.
And so oil is roughly fairly priced in terms of gold.
所以从黄金的角度来看,石油的定价大致公平。
And even in terms of dollars, you know, oil was spiked up to like 140, you know, a decade and a half ago. And even from till seven all the way to 2014, it was like an average price that was equal or higher than it is now.
It had values during the global financial crisis. It had crazy peaks over 100. And, you know, it eventually fell off a cliff after it got a supply glut from that shale we talked about.
But really, at the current time, it's not that expensive. Now, European gas is, you know, that's horrifyingly expensive. And so there are and coal had a huge gigantic spike in price. So there are types of energy that are expensive. The oil market has not yet reached that point.
I think it's, you know, the years ahead, it's probably going higher. And, you know, to your prior point, it's I think there's a lot of issues around managing to expectations rather than managing to outcomes, which is, you know, trying to obfuscate, get anything dirty off the balance sheet rather than making it not exist.
You just say, it's not our you don't want it on our balance sheet because we have a bureaucratic quota to meet.
你只是说,不是因为我们不希望它出现在我们的资产负债表上,而是因为我们有一个官僚配额要满足。
And so there's there was an example of, you know, European like they were chopping down old growth forests in Canada and then shipping those wood pellets. And that's like a irreplaceable deep carbon sink, you know, biodiversity naturally occurring. It's not one of those like, you know, human planted forests that we just keep turning ground. It's like old growth.
And we're shipping those wood pellets to burn over in Europe. And that's counted as green. And that's about that's one of the least green things I can think of. And that's an example of managing to optics.
Whereas managing to outcomes is like, you know, more of an engineering mindset. How can we make this grid stable? How can we make the air clean? How can we, you know, balance these different optimization goals and not just push it on to some other balance sheet or put out of mind?
The problem is that if a place does not have affordable energy, it becomes uncompetitive very quickly. And so if you're we've had, you know, in Europe, you guys have had like some facilities shutting down, you know, fertilizer plants, aluminum plants and things like that, because they're just no longer competitive at those electricity prices. And so that can help put a cap on electricity prices, but also puts a cap on economic growth and likely triggers recessionary conditions.
And so an environment that can't get those cheap energy prices quickly becomes uncompetitive in the global market. And Europe has been a strong manufacturer. So that's important to manage properly. You know, some countries that are more service oriented can get away with higher energy prices. But if you're manufacturing base, it's a little bit more cute. And then of course, any consumer, if they have to spend more money on their energy bill, especially they're spending more on energy.
And then that's revenue for another country, because you're not producing it locally. That's less money you can spend on local goods and services. And so that's bad for the economy. And so that's the environment that many countries are in. So right now the dollar is pretty strong relative to other currencies. So actual oil is pretty highly priced in euro terms pound or yen and a lot of frontier markets, you know, not necessarily some of the major emerging markets, they've actually held up better. But compared to a lot of currencies, oil is very highly priced. And it is putting a lot of pressure. And then it's like I said, especially the natural gas, especially electricity prices, the coal. And so it's a matter of competitors and displacement of more discretionary purchases.
Yeah, that's so true. And you know, a country like Germany speaking about manufacturing, it's just in the world of pain. And even whenever you look at the gas storage, like what they can hold, it's just it looks tricky at what's going to happen throughout the winter. So you already have all these contingency plan, what's going to happen if equity happens. And the last place you're going to cut is households. I'm not saying it's not reasonable. Obviously, it's also insensitive in terms of, you know, voters, like voters tend to vote more than say companies. And so like that's also another place where you have to consider it. But it seems like it's going to be, well, I think Europe has been lying for at least two decades. And here we are, it seems more grim than ever. But anyways, then we follow Warren Buffett and his investments quite closely here on the show. And Buffett recently built a 25 billion position in Chevron equivalent to an 8% ish ownership, and almost a 30% stake in accidental 30%. I don't know if anyone's take up these numbers, but Buffett also had a lot of warrants there. So that's why I came up with that number 30. If you only look at common stock, it's 20 ish plus what are your thoughts on the two stocks at the current market price?
So long term, I'm bullish on them. Chevron is one of the more expensive ones, but it's also one of the higher quality, safe liquid ones. And so, you know, my approach has been more kind of geographic diversification and more different oil types. So I have, you know, I have some of that kind of company. I also have some of the Canadian companies, you know, I think that there are other ones around the world. I've also been like some of the pipelines. He also bought, you know, they bought a pipeline from a company, right?
So it's about energy producers and infrastructure. I think like any good value investor, and he's of course, you know, legendary for it. He knows what's cheap and he knows what's under invested in, and it's kind of an anti-bubble in many ways. And so I think he's been smart to get into the energy space. And, you know, obviously with his size of his book, he's going to go for the big liquid, you know, longer duration type of projects.
And then also, I mean, he, you know, a couple years ago, he did those Japanese trading companies. So you put a few billion dollars into those. And those are many ways, they're commodity oriented, hard asset, you know, and some of them have energy exposure. So, and if you kind of tally up his overall kind of commodity energy, you know, even the infrastructure from moving it, like pipeline, he's made a pretty big bet on energy. And I think that's smart because, you know, he's obviously he's got that Apple position. It's very tech oriented. He's got the banks. And so, you know, I think he wanted to add to the real asset side of his book and specifically in areas that are underinvested in.
So it's kind of, especially when he started doing them, it was less, you know, it's a little bit more contrarian than it was now. And a lot of, you know, sometimes he has criticized for not being super early. Like when he bought Apple, people were like, Apple, really, it's one of the biggest companies. It's already done great. And of course, it did amazing after that. So, you know, when he started getting into those oil companies, they already did pretty well. He didn't like buy them at the bottom in like March 2020. They were like, you know, I was in that kind of over. And I think we're in the beginning of like, five, 10 year story here for some of these companies, just the sector in general. And I think he sees that and that he's setting a Berkshire to, you know, be well positioned for that.
Yeah, I think you absolutely right, Lynn. And Chevron isn't priced cheaply, as you said. There's also a limited number of even for Buffett, you know, or especially for Buffett, of companies you can invest in. You know, if you're sitting $140 billion of cash, which most of us don't, you can't, you know, because there are more exciting energy companies out there for sure. But you know, if the market is a billion dollars, it's just not going to move the needle. But I wanted to talk about Opig Plus. It's been making headlines here recently.
Opig Plus is a castle of all producing the countries, including Russia, Saudi Arabia, two of the biggest. And they recently cut productions by two million barrels per day. For comparison, they produce 40 million barrels daily. And I just wanted to give you some approximate numbers for everyone to follow. So the total oil market is around 100 million barrels. US has just showed up 20 million barrels per day. Just so like whenever we are like throwing out these numbers, there's something to compare it to. Anyways, why is explicitly not said, it seems like the members want a floor under the price of all between called 100 to like 80 to 100 compared to say 70 to 80 per barrel before COVID. What can the Western world do to lower the price of oil? And do we even buy the premise of my question?
So I would have reframed the question a little bit. So when Opig cut, when they did that two million cut, it's actually technically not a production cut. It's a cut for the ceiling for how much they can produce.
And what's interesting is they were already deeply under, they're already missing it underperforming that ceiling. And if you go back to Opig historically, it's actually been the problem of the other way around. Like they said a ceiling and then their, you know, countries are kind of going over it, trying to sell a little extra around the margins, you know, kind of cheating a little bit. And so it's actually a matter of enforcing not going above it.
Whereas in this environment, there's been the opposite where, you know, the majority of Opig countries or a bunch of Opig countries are failing to even meet their ceiling. And there's been good research by a number of firms that, you know, specialize in energy, you know, kind of all out more than I do. And they've done like the detailed work on analyzing some of these countries. And they've argued that there, a lot of these are near capacity, that, you know, that with the current level of CAPEX and some, sometimes, in some cases, just the amount of reserves they have and just overall kind of maximum output they can do, that they're kind of tapped out, you know, and there's a little bit around the margins, maybe, but they don't have the gigantic swing production that many people think they do, which is different than history.
And then some, you know, they might have to trim the production ceiling, you know, if you keep feeling to meet your production targets, eventually, countries realize you don't have what you say you have. And so this is, you know, I think one way of managing the optics is also the question, because we're talking about Opig Plus, which is, which includes Russia, you know, due to the war, the Western oil companies have had to pull out, they had capital and equipment and expertise that was part of Russia's production. And so the question is, we talked about oil declines, you know, what happens in a year to years, three years, if they can't recoup that level of investment to keep that production as high or higher than it is now, you could see a mild fall off in Russian production, for example.
And so I think it's actually more matter of Opig not fully having the ability to keep amping it up. Then there's also matter of geopolitical alliances, deteriorating conditions between US and Saudi relations. And so essentially what that is saying though, is that there is a floor there, they're willing to defend that floor, but also that they might, you know, they might not just have a lot of spare capacity.
And you know, there are ways, you know, North America and Europe do have oil and gas reserves that you can tap into. I know in Europe, they've run into some earthquakes. So you know, somebody's saying that sometimes there's environmental groups that say we don't want to tap into this. In the United States, Biden has issued an order of magnitude fewer drilling permits for federal lands within the first 19 months of his administration compared to any post World War II administration. And that's part of his campaign program. He didn't want drilling on federal lands as prior to an acute energy crisis.
And so now you have that dichotomy between, you know, you made a promise, but then you want to get inflation under control, then there's that. There's also a matter of, there's only so much refining and transportation capacity, right? So in the United States, you're pretty cheap natural gas. The question is, why can't we just send that all over to Europe? And of course, the problem is you need LNG infrastructure, which is expensive and time consuming to build.
And then even if we get it there, then you need import LNG infrastructure and you need to like have then the transportation to get that from the coast to the points where you need it. And so it's a matter of that type of infrastructure. It's a matter of refining. So you can have all the oil you want. But if you only have so much diesel production capacity, you can have a diesel shortage, even if oil's cheap, right? So there's multiple parts, there's multiple bottlenecks along the path to get right.
So one thing that that North American or Europe, like Western countries can do, one is they could expand their exploration and production around the margins. They also can invest in more infrastructure, transportation, refining, things like that.
In the United States, we've not added a new refinery in like 50 years. We've expanded existing refineries. And that's because they're not the most environmentally friendly sites. And there's always opposition, not in my backyard, no more refineries. And it's like, well, there is a trade-off for that. Either you have to import more of that product, or you're going to have shortages and high prices of that product if demand does not fall off with your capped or slow growing supply. And so there are investments that can be done. And I think it's one of those things where when the price signals emerge immediately, maybe there's the idea that it's transitory or you can blame the blame someone. But if it goes on month after month, quarter after quarter year of year, eventually that starts to change how people vote. It changes how politicians draw the numbers. They want to stay in power. That changes how companies will choose to invest longer-term capital. And they say, okay, this shortage is here to stay. Let me be a little bit more aggressive here now. And so price eventually can solve a lot of things. And it just takes time. And it takes working through some of the headwinds that are present at the current time.
Yeah. And I don't want this into you too much to come across as a lot of complaining about the India, Maggis and Europe, even though it's probably too late. But it just seems like there were no plan B. Like you mentioned before, we can't just, one of the first things you must suggest is, oh, the US should just like ship us like a lot in G and we just didn't have the infrastructure to like receive it. So there's so much of that infrastructure that isn't, it just isn't built out. And something that's just always under invested is the power grid. It doesn't sell well to voters. And if you say, oh, let's just have a better power grid. Because what does that mean? Like I can still charge my iPhone and I can still like have lights in my home and like, but that's just not how it works. And so, so what happens is like the power grid is just a mess. And they're a mess for so many reasons. Like we like to think, I don't know if I can come up with the best example of, you know, whenever we cook too much food and kind of feel like, Oh my God, it would be so great if someone could like take the spoons or don't have to throw it out. So like almost the same analogy I want to say, but in India, because we have so much energy that's being produced, and we have so much to go to waste. And one of the reasons, there are many reasons why a lot of it goes to waste is that the power grid just can't handle it. And it takes a lot of time to build out. So it's not like, Oh, there's a war now in Ukraine and like, let's just build out the power grid. No, it takes a lot of time and to for power grids to be very efficient.
Well, it's slightly different in the States, even though I also know you also have issues with your power grid. But like, that's one country. It's really difficult in Europe because something like a power grid is just so crucial to infrastructure. So whenever you're building things together, there's just so many different conflicts you need to hash out. And also to your point before, not a lot of people want to have upgraded the power grid in their backyard. Like, no, no, we want we want better power grid. So we're not depending on Russia, just not where I live. But I still want the benefits. And that's just the nature of how we are as people, I guess.
Yeah, there's been both in the United States and in Europe, there's a problem with construction in general. It's just there's a lot of headwinds for doing it. And like you point out, there's not a lot of incentive to run on a campaign of stronger grids unless you're experiencing like rolling blackouts.
So once the problem has to get severe before it becomes a voter issue, and at that point, it takes years to fix. So that's just how that works. And the funny stat that we have is the United States, it took like a year to build the Empire State Building in the 30s. We can't build a skyscraper any year now. We can barely build one in five years. If you try to build like high speed rail, good luck, give it a decade and you'll still have like the permitting being done. It's just a lot of these a lot of countries are now it's very challenging to build these infrastructure projects. And that includes modernizing the grid.
So a lot of these goals, they want to electrify things more. Right now, you can call it almost decentralized energy. So you have, let's say, you know, my house has electrical power. It also has a natural gas line. And then also my car goes to a gas lane, which is a whole another distribution point. Right. So all those there's three different energy distribution points that are basically going to my home and my consumption.
And the idea is we want to fold that all into just electricity. Right. So instead of using natural gas for my heating or my stove, a lot of communities are saying only electric now. So that's that gets forward into the electric power. And then they say, okay, now we want to do EVs only electric vehicles. And so that that whole like gasoline, you know, transport infrastructure that gets forward into the grid. Right. And so then suddenly, instead of three different channels of energy, I'm relying on one channel of energy. That better be a super robust type of energy or trans energy transportation electricity, because if it's not, if it's not ready for that, or if it goes down, you know, all off everything goes down instead of having three different types of energy. And so that that's I think the challenge with this long term plan of electrification and also the just the ability even outside of energies, the ability for kind of wealthy developed countries that already have a lot of infrastructure to build it or place that existing infrastructure. It's just a very costly, very bureaucratic, very, very challenging thing to do for a variety of reasons.
Yeah. And just one last comment on that. You know, we can build that grid above the ground, but people just don't want that. It doesn't look nice. It's a cheaper option because if you dig into the ground, which you can also do is just so expensive because you have this radius, a lot of heat. So it's like, it's just a very expensive thing to do. And then you have the incentive, like with a different country. So let give you like one example, like France, they've been providing us all this wonderful electricity and they're run on nuclear. And so we have this thing where a lot of countries, so for example, Germany, like the green party do not want nuclear. And I not want to go in like pro-akon. I'm just saying that if you don't want that, it's completely fine. Then you just need to use a fossil fuel because right now the renewables can't just, they're just not stable enough to do it. And even in Germany, they have three different grids.
I know it's, I probably make this way too nerdy, but I had different grids and they're not connected. If that's enough room on the cable, you just can't get that electricity. So you have so much electricity that go to waste for so many reasons.
Anyways, at least we do another question here, then can we fix inflation before we fix the engine markets? I think not persistently. Now, if you cause a deep enough recession and suppress demand enough, you know, if enough business is shut down due to high energy costs, if you create enough unemployment to suppress wage increases, then you can cure inflation, but it's like cutting off your leg to fix the infection. That's not what the patient asked for. What people really kind of think mean when they say that or like, I think that what they should mean is how can you get back to a period of dis-explationary growth? And I think that's only possible once you fix the energy situation. And even then there's some pressures. There's, you know, we had a multi-decade trend of globalization towards places like China, and that's stalling out or in some cases reversing, just due to one is demographics. And, you know, we've already filled that bucket now. And also, there's, of course, geopolitical tensions and reasons and things like that.
So I think the short interest is, you know, I've been describing like holding a beach pole underwater. You can, you know, you can temporarily hold it down. You can drain the strategic petroleum reserve. You can, you know, China's doing recurring lockdowns, which is actually suppressing quite a bit of fuel demand. You can do, you know, you can tighten monetary policy so much that no one's building homes and electricity prices can get a control and shut down fertilizer and in metals companies. And you can, you can kind of press that down by having demand kind of fall to meet, meet supply.
The problem is then you, you start to get recession. You start to get unrest. And if you then try to stimulate you out of that, well, that, those shortages are still there, structurally. If you have not taken that time to increase supply. And another challenging thing is that all these rate hike increases, admirables, they are, they increase the cost of capital for energy companies. And so the hurdle rate for them choosing to do a new project is even higher now. And so it's actually, it's suppressing demand, but it's also pressing in some cases supply arguably. And so we're in an environment where until they, you know, until we grind through this, until we actually fix the energy situation, I don't think you're going to get disinflation or growth kind of bouncing between either you're going to get inflation or you're going to get recessionary like conditions with, you know, maybe lower inflation, but nobody wants that either.
Then the period we're in, it's, it's often in the financial media compared with the 1970s, early 1980s, giving how central banks are raising rates and fighting inflation. Now the fight wasn't equally distributed if we were looking across the globe. From 1978 to 1984, Britain, Germany, and Japan cut their budget deficits while hiking rates in Canada and France did the same thing, though, not to the same extent. The US was the exception of the major economies because they were hiking rates, but they were cutting taxes during the Reagan administration. And many economists today argue that while Paul Vogler got the credit, the inflation environment didn't structurally change before the monetary and fiscal policy worked in tandem.
Do you agree with that assessment? And I guess depending on your answer, how does that translate into today's environment in Western Europe and the US, where we are hiking rates, but we're also running huge deficits?
Yeah, I mostly agree. Also, the inflation in earlier, resolved itself in the 70s until they fixed the energy situation, going back to the prior question. Right. So you had multiple energy shocks in the 70s, and by the 80s, those were largely sorted out. And so the combination of tight monetary policy, and then the energy situation resolved, that helped that went a long way. It wasn't just Volcker. And then you have the fiscal situation is interesting because so Reagan did boost the deficits a lot, but it's like the deficit as a percentage of GDP we have now in the US are bigger than most periods back then. Right. So even that it's not just direction that matters, it's also magnitude.
And so that's actually why I've used the 1940s comparison where, you know, in the 70s, if you look at so broad money supply was growing pretty quickly. And money supply mostly is created from either bank lending or monetized fiscal deficits. And in the 70s, the majority of the money supply growth was coming from bank lending. That was a kind of a peak demographic situation. You know, baby boomers were entering early adulthood, consuming buying houses, getting jobs. And so that was a, you know, demand driven bank lending driven type of inflation environment. And then we added fuel onto the fire with like, you know, wars, guns and butter programs, right? So that we did add some deficits to that. But that actually was the minority monetary creation direction. Whereas like in the 1940s, you also had insane money supply growth, but it wasn't because of bank lending. It was because of massive fiscal deficits to fight the war. And most of fighting the war means building facilities, hiring people, trying to make like gun chips, right, or like supply chains and things like that. So it's actually, it's a type of fiscal stimulus, even though the outcome is in many cases wasted. But when they come back, a lot of that could be repurposed domestically to make cars and to make other industrial things.
And so in that environment, that was a very inflation environment regards to what the central banks wanted to do. And so I think the issue now is that we're in more of a 1940s environment where, you know, the past two, three years, most of the money supply growth has come from monetized fiscal deficits to deal with some of these shocks that are happening and to deal with the fact that the system so levered that they'd rather print and let kind of defaults happen in a, you know, kind of a fragile economy.
Now, if you zoom in on the current time, because of the monetary tightening, you know, money supply growth is not growing very quickly. In the US anymore, it's been rather flat. And so that gets part of why we're getting this kind of contraction in a number of sectors and things like that. But the longer term story, I think for this decade is that the money supply growth is coming from the fiscal side. And so as long as that's unaddressed, and as long as the energy situation is unaddressed, money tightening can only do so much. It can hold the beach ball under the water for periods of time, but all that upward pressure on the beach ball is from those other two forces.
And I'd even go further say even the fiscal budget, it's very hard for them to solve at this point because a lot of it is demographics entitlement driven type of spending, a lot of it's locked in. And then if they cut, you know, many cases like the GDP growth figures we look at, that includes those deficits. So when you trim the deficits, in many cases, you trim the GDP growth. So if you're trying to optimize for like debt to GDP, basically austerity works in terms of preventing you from accumulating debt. But once you're over, you know, 100% sovereign debt to GDP, austerity usually is unable to push it back down. You're kind of already past that event horizon.
And so I think that's kind of the environment where in the 2020s where this is going to be a persistently inflationary force, but you know, perhaps with periods of disinflationary, fight back, hold the beach ball under the water type of environment that I think we're now. And there seems to be some rumors that we don't need to perhaps hold the beach ball too long under the water. At least there've been some rumors around that the inflation target might be abandoned of 2%. There seems to be at least some that suggest a 3% or 4% target rate. This is not like an official announcement from the Fed or ECB, anything like that. It's just some economists that had some fun about exploring that. But some people have to have noticed and it would be different implications if that inflation target would be changed. Of course, it would inflate some of the, it weighed some of the long-term public debt. It would also lead to a redistribution from greater to a debtor. And it would probably also lower trust in central banks.
Now, if we just, if we just threw me at Lynn here and say this plays out that we're going to change this inflation target for central banks in the western world. What are the implications for us as investors and citizens if inflation structurally moves higher or the target moves higher? Yes, it's a good question. I mean, briefly going back to why they would go that. So Volcker, for example, under his watch when he did his big tightening, federal debt to GP was 30%. And so Powell's dealing with 130%. So he's trying to do the Volcker playbook, but he's up against forces that even Volcker didn't have to deal with.
And so let's say we fast forward and they're unable to tighten, at least in such a way that they get back to disinflation or growth. They keep choosing between either recession or inflation. They can't manage to get disinflation or growth because of the structural force we talked about. If they then resort to higher average inflation targeting, I think that causes a number of issues. One, that's kind of like partially letting go to the beach ball a little bit. So I think some of those more value-oriented, hard assets type of things do well. So that could be cash flow producing things like energy producers and pipelines and chemical companies and refined. These harder asset under-invested areas, it can also mean hard monies like gold or Bitcoin, catch a bid as you have a recurrence of currency debasement and perceptions around forward strength of the fiat currency, people that want alternatives.
One thing that's challenging is going back to the 40s and thereafter, when they did that financial repression playbook of hold rates, basically let inflation run hot compared to interest rates, eventually people won out. So there's that IMF paper by Reinehart, Carmen Reinehart, and it was like, I think she phrased it, you need a captive audience. If you're going to inflate the data way, you've got to keep people in the debt. If your money is going to lose value, how do you keep people in the money? To a lesser extent, this happens in emerging markets all the time. How do you keep people in the local currency? They all want dollars. They all want gold or dollars or other assets or stable coins or Bitcoin, whatever the case may be. They want whatever it is, they don't want the Argentine paste though, that's for sure. So the problem is generally you turn to capital controls.
So the United States, for example, they banned gold for 40 years. You could go to jail for 10 years for owning a benign yellow medal. That's what they turned to. You also had just, back then, there was just obviously worse technology. So you had less information traveling around. You had it was harder to move money around. The question is, what happens when you run a financial or a pression playbook in the modern environment of social media? Easier ways to move money. I think that's a new experiment we're going to encounter. I don't think anyone can fully tell you how it's going to work out. I think generally money tries to move towards what is not being debased, which I think would again be a variety of scarce assets, some cashflow producing some more monetary, but it's whatever is perceived as outside of that capital audience, the basic situation.
I think that, Lynn, if you read about capital controls, it looks good on paper, but in fact, it's really difficult to enforce. You just almost seem to have this shadow economy going on. If you go back to the whole thing about leading up to Nixon taking at the US as well, and the world of the gold standard, the price of gold went from $35 to $800. I want to say in January of 1980, it was fast that moved. You saw whenever capital control was applied in Southeast Asia, whenever they tried to restrict capital, taking out of the country in the late 90s, how they just crashed the economy. It's just very difficult to do in practice. Like you mentioned before, in today's world, it's probably even more difficult than it's ever been before. Transitioning into the next topic.
Also recently, you would think that when the Fed were buying treasuries, it pushes down the yield. But that's actually not the case. Could you please elaborate on this? What seems to be a very counterintuitive relationship? So the prior decade, QE was intended in part to suppress yields. It was one of the tools that they were using. But when actually people crunched the numbers, they found that at the time of purchases, that was not the case. You'd actually have an environment of yields going up.
The way I like to structure it, the way I frame it at least, is it's a different between long-term and short-term. The short-term is that when they're not buying, financial conditions are tighter, economies slowing, financial markets are tighter, and a lot of risk assets are not doing great, and people buy bonds. When the central bank starts buying, it really liquefies the market. It eases financial conditions. You see, you get an uptick in risk assets. People buy those and they sell the bonds. So even though the Fed's buying, the central banks are buying the private sector selling. They're saying, okay, sold to you. And so in the near-term, it actually has the counterintuitive opposite effect. People wouldn't expect that the biggest buyer buys a product, the price goes down, you'll go up. You would not expect that, but that's how it works. But if you zoom out, the question is, let's say the Fed wanted to sell $2 trillion in treasuries that decade. Could they have done it without destroying the price? I would argue, many would argue no. That even though the moment they buy it, it's actually not the price you actually expect that the cumulative effect of taking that excess supply off the market was important for holding down yields. Now that we're seeing more inflationary pressures, and we have debt at higher levels relative to GDP, and there's just supply of those bond issuances, a lot of people were insisting that once the central bank's tried to tighten, that's not bad for yields. But if you're actually doing supply-demand analysis of who's in a buy that is so much of who's in a buy it, right now we're in an environment where yields are going up as the central bank has in many cases pulled back their purchases. That's more in line with intuition. I think that's more in line with the fact that we have an inflation environment and we have more acute oversupply.
Actually, that relationship started breaking down in March 2020, because during the COVID crash, first, it went how you'd expect, which is people's soul stocks, right? They're like, okay, we don't know what's going to happen. Let's get to Treasuries, and then it got so bad, and the dollar spiked because all these cash flows were on the world were drying up, but they still have dollar-dominated debt to service. So this is scrambled for dollars and safe haven to that.
So every screen link for dollars, and then the problem is that countries with dollar-dominated debt, they have to sell assets to get dollars to service the debt. So where they sell, they sell Treasuries. And so basically people bought Treasuries as old stocks until it crashed so hard and got so illiquid, and the dollar spiked so much that they forced soul Treasuries and it broke the Treasury market.
The off-the-run Treasury market went totally liquid. There's no bid. And you actually started to get yield spiking from a very low level at the worst point in that sell-off, which is when you think there'd be maximum demand for Treasuries. And that's, again, it's just a mechanical supply demand problem at that point. And so that's when the Federal Reserve had to come in and buy a trillion dollars of Treasuries in three weeks, and they hammered down that little spike and they fixed the liquidity situation.
That was kind of the first sign of a trend change that this is not the 2010s situation. This is more a sovereign debt crisis situation. It's different. And that's really materialized here in 2022, which is we've gotten past, I think, that disinflationary commodity over supply cycle that was, I've used the analog of the 1930s compared to the 2010s just without the dust bull and the better technology. So it's more fun, but it's still kind of the static inflationary deleveraging period.
And now we're in the 2020s, which is, unfortunately, more like the 1940s, which is massive fiscal spending, rising geopolitical tensions, outright war, in some cases, unfortunately. The analogy got more literal than when I originally made that analogy. And that's more inflation environment and that's an environment where stocks and bonds can go down together if the central banks are not monetizing that debt because they have trouble placing that debt.
So right now you have, as long as the dollar is strong, four sectors not buying treasuries, in fact, they're trimming their treasuries to defend their own currency. It's not that their opinion is that treasuries are overvalued. It's just a mechanical outcome. It's like, hey, we want to defend the yen. We're going to not buy treasuries. We're going to trim some treasuries. That's how it is. Then you have feds not, they're letting them treasure them to show up the balance sheet. And you have SLR regulations being that commercial banks can only buy so many treasuries.
So the three biggest balance sheets are net flat to down and there's still issuance that all these smaller balance sheets have to absorb them somehow. And that's how you get disorderly liquid conditions with higher yields and lower prices. And so I think that 2020 is marked by sovereign debt problems and currency problems. Not necessarily, the prior one it blew up in the banking sector and the private leverage sector. Whereas now I think it's more sovereign debt currencies and then that underlying energy because you can't print energy.
Yeah, it is so interesting that you make this comparison to the 1940s. And not like everyone else would say, well, high inflation, well, we had that in the 70s and early 80s. And so I really like that you're such a student of history.
Then the world is no short of pundits who want to give power advice. And I'm definitely guilty as charged. Generally, whenever we talk about the call optimal monetary policy, I kind of like want to use the analogy that is it's as wrong as whenever a person would ask you, perhaps, what should I invest in? Because the answer is really it depends on what's your goal.
So if I'm turning the table here, and of course also parting out the irony that I'm now asking you to give to give Paul a friendly advice, I would change that question by asking, depending on what Paul wants to optimize for, what should he do with monetary policy? It's a good set of questions. And I like, I have different answers depending on timeframes or how fundamental I am in my thinking, which is my kind of bedrock answer is that I'm not a fan of price controls, and that includes the price of money.
So I actually kind of contest the whole notion of the modern central banking works. United States is a country of 330 million people. Do I think that there's one interest rate that is suitable for the entire country? Is the interest rate for rural Alabama the same rate as New York? Should this be set by a small committee of elders?
So I would say no. I kind of just throw the model, but that is the model we live in. That's the model that we operate in. So then the question becomes, what do you do with that model? So I think if if Paul's trying to optimize for inflation, which he's actually kind of legally mandated to do, he's got really three mandates. One is low unemployment, which he's got officially the way they measure it, then it's stable pricing, which they define as 2% average inflation. They're currently way above target, the way they measure it. So he's got to get that down in terms of mandates. And then they have kind of the third shadow mandate of financial stability. So the treasury market blows up. They have no choice but to go in and fix that before it melts down.
So he's got a clear mandate, which is increase unemployment and decrease inflation. So I think using the limited tools he has, he's kind of forced to do what he's supposed to do. So I'm not really sure what I would do different if I was Powell, because I think it's almost an insolvable problem. It's like, how do you advise to solve an insolvable problem or kind of a bad algorithm for what you're supposed to do?
So in general, I think in this environment, only solving for inflation is the wrong problem. And instead, it's how to get disinflationary growth, which is mostly not a central bank question. It's mostly a private sector and fiscal policy question. It's mostly, how do you get more energy supply? How do you get more infrastructure? That kind of thing. And that's not something Powell has any control over. He's even said we have no control over food and energy prices. So that might be even a hint at average inflation targeting. If they just can't get the energy situation under control, and they're like, well, we killed rents at least. So that's best we could do.
So I think there's only so much any central banker can do. It's the Kobyashim Roo for people that know Star Trek, the insolvable situation. And so I think that's kind of what they're in. And the only way around that is probably eventually to change some of the mandates or to redefine how you interpret the mandates, which can include things like different levels of inflation targeting.
And I think the longer term story is I would like to see better technology so that there's not a committee of a handful of elders setting an interest rate for 330 million people in a manual process. I mean, you see things like they do interviews and they're like, well, we're going to pencil some interest rate hikes in and we're going to say, that's how we're running. We're in the 21st century and we're penciling interest rates. We're penciling and basically price controls for the price that sets all other prices.
And so different answers for different timeframes, I guess. But I feel bad for Powell. I don't know what I would do differently. No, there are choices and consequences. And he's just trapped between a rug and a half place. Someone will get mad at him regardless of what he do. Exactly. Yeah, sure. And before the line, you said 330 million people. I am almost inclined to say eight billion. Because you're actually, yeah.
I mean, yeah, because we hear that the US is exporting inflation. Given the continuous interest rate hikes, could you please help us understand what does mean whenever we hear the US is exporting inflation? And what is the implication of the US monetary policy to the world?
So most commodities are priced in dollars.
So the dollars strength compared to most currencies, that's making them harder to afford in their local currencies.
In addition, most global financing happens in dollars.
So if an entity in Europe wants to finance some Latin American debt, either government debt or corporate debt, there's a good chance it'll be in dollars.
There's some in euros, but it's a distant second compared to dollars.
And so when Powell or anyone at the Fed, when they tighten monetary policy, they're basically hardening the dollar and then they're hardening everyone's liabilities.
So in addition, as you point out correctly, in addition to affecting 330 million Americans, you have an entity over in Turkey or Sri Lanka or Brazil or China, a country XYZ, they're getting squeezed due to a decision by a council in another country.
Because they've, for network effects, for global hegemony reasons, for all sorts of historical reasons, and also just the fact that they haven't found a better alternative, they're using another country's money and assets as their money or their reserve asset or their debt financing.
And they get squeezed by that.
They're basically subject to that foreign power.
And so when the dollar strength ends, it can help us get inflation under control, but it's actually making it worse for the periphery.
That's kind of how this whole system's been designed, which is to push volatility to the periphery.
So the core is the US, the secondary ring is like all the other leading developed countries.
And then the periphery is especially the emerging market in frontier countries.
We just push volatility to them, which many would say unjust, but that's how the system's designed.
And that can work as long as the treasure market is functioning, because the feedback loop, one thing that has happened over time, for example, in 1980s, when Volcker tightened, it broke Latin America, which basically calls all these debt and currency crisis down there.
There's big contributing factor to that.
Whereas now, a lot of those countries have more reserves than they had back then.
And then another example, actually a stronger example is late 90s, strong dollar broke Southeast Asia.
It broke their situation.
Now, especially Southeast Asia has very strong reserves.
They've learned their lesson, and they've accumulated a lot of reserves during good times.
And so when the dollar strengthens, they have a lot of reserves that they can use to defend their currency and sell.
And then the question becomes, who breaks first?
Is it the whole world or is it the treasure market?
And the answer is a little, I think a little bit both, because the periphery unfortunately still breaks first.
The poorest countries, the frontier markets, they just don't have the reserve, they have the debts, they have just weak pricing for the input commodities they need.
So they unfortunately break first.
But then it becomes a question of major emerging markets versus the US.
So the question is, can Japan and China sell more treasuries than the US private sector can buy?
And so they each have a trillion dollars of treasuries, give or take.
And then you add Switzerland, it's another developed country.
But then you go into emerging markets and you have Taiwan, they have a ton of US assets, Brazil has decent amount of US assets, and they also have commodity exports.
And so it becomes that it is a global kind of that type of knot.
I forget the name of it, it's like all tied up together.
And how do you unfold that knot?
And I think the thing to watch is the treasure market, because there are feedback loops here.
That goes back to the impossible question.
Paul doesn't have complete control over what he does, because he's got limitations like the treasure market and things like that that he's got to deal with.
And so it becomes, how far can you push it?
How many twists or tools can he do it in his shop?
Keep the treasure market functioning while he's trying to tighten elsewhere.
And so yeah, basically we live in a system where we do our best to push volatility to the poorest of the world, the periphery.
Yeah, and if we look at emerging markets, they're definitely in a world of pain in so many ways.
But to your point before, it is interesting that they have stronger reserves, they learn a lot from what happened in the 90s.
And one of the things that they also learned was to have less debt and dominated in dollars, which just gets so much more expensive whenever the dollar gets expensive and because of high grades.
Because I was still surprised knowing that to learn that many emerging currencies, including the currencies of Brazil, Mexico, Peru, have performed better than the US dollar over the past 12 months or at least this year.
And much better than the traditional seen strong occurrences like Euro pound at the yen.
Of course, we could also like point to currencies like the Turkish lira and say, well, it doesn't go for all emerging markets.
But I still want to point out the irony that many emerging markets are forced to be more hawkers when times get tough than the more developed economies. Why is that? Because historically, they have the weaker currencies. They're the ones that are more prone to currency crisis.
And so they have to be hawkish. And that means the US gets the luxury, usually, of easing into a recession and tightening into a stronger economy. But there's a lot of emerging markets have to tighten into a weak economy just to defend from a currency crisis because the defense tightening. Right? So they have to defend against the fact that the rich people of the world are trying to push volatility to them. And they have to use their reserves and also tightness to try their best to defend against that. And over time, some emerging markets have matured. They've entered the higher level of emerging markets. And so they build up more reserves and they have more resilience. So when people just say, quote, emerging markets, as though it's one group, it's actually very different groups. And so, ironically, why a lot of the bigger emerging markets are holding a better than the developed country currencies this year is because right now, it's, a lot of them have decent reserves and they've been pretty hawkish.
And so the areas of weakness are countries that have either a combination of energy inputs. They're now higher priced. So they've they worst in their current account bounce. And they have so much debt that they can't raise interest rates properly. So that includes like Japan, that includes parts of Europe. And so those are the ones you're seeing a lot of of crisis in.
Whereas Brazil, they front ran the Fed, they jacked up interest rates super high. They also have a decent commodity situation, obviously. And so they're not being as punished as some of these Western sovereigns or these developed XUS sovereigns. But you still have Turkey, they have a lot of dollar-damaged debt. They don't have a lot of reserves. And then they have unusual beliefs about interest rates. So they're super high inflation and they don't want to tighten the interest rates. And so until you kind of fix the energy situation, the fiscal situation, and you know, positive rates, it's hard for that currency to fully stabilize. And so it comes in very country by country specific issue rather than develop markets versus emerging markets. Because even among developed countries, there are some that are, they have a ton of reserves, maybe their energy sufficient, right? And so they're doing okay. And so it becomes more about the energy and the debt.
Yeah, and just one quick comment to what Argan is doing in Turkey, he has this weird relationship about, he feels that a lower interest rate gives you the win inflation. So that's the way he wants to go about it. He keeps on firing central banker after central banker until he can find someone who agrees with him. And two quick points on that. One is that Warren Moser, who is credit is kind of like founded in the MMT school, his advice to Turkey is to cut interest to zero. Right? So, so Argan is not alone in that belief. Number two, it's basically the fiat system does not work well with that. There's different ways to interpret that obviously. So there's different, different sub-interpretations of that. But that's, there is kind of that cultural context there. And most, a lot of countries have to just ignore that to function within the modern banking system. And so, you know, I hesitate to kind of make fun of it too much. But it's just a challenging environment when someone has these, has beliefs like that around interest rates and it's being tested in the world about, you know, laws that, for example, were written while gold was money is different than when Turkish lira is money. Right? And so, it's just a challenging situation for some of these countries to navigate.
Well, S Linn, is there, before we end this, this interview and, and, and I definitely want to give you a handoff too, is there anything you feel that we haven't covered in this, in this interview?
I think, I think we covered quite a bit. I think it's just, it's, it's about, you know, going forward, it's obviously going to be volatile in a lot of ways. And, you know, I think it's just a support of folks in the fundamentals, you know, disinflationary growth generally comes when your necessary input costs are cheap and abundant, which is things like commodities and basic labor. And there's, you know, there's freedom to innovate and grow and, and, and increase productivity, right? So when people had to farm by hand, then they got tools, and they got tractors, and then maybe get self driving tractors, right? You keep it, you, you've, you've, you keep increasing the, the productivity of a per farmer basis to feed the rest of the world. And that, that applies industry after industry after industry. And when you go through, you know, the long arc of history is, especially once we discovered like, you know, hydrocarbons and these denture energy sources, there's been this upward trend of more and more productivity. And, but there are, there are periods of setback, you know, there are, there are, you know, wars, for example, are, are very malinvestment. They, they're inflationary. Same thing with like, you know, if there's, if there's things that prevent productivity from increasing, things that prevent business from, from functioning that can, that can suppress productivity. Then if you have under investment in those input costs, those like, raw commodities, that's, that's inflationary. That's, it's bad for productivity. It's, it's more expensive to afford basic things that we were affording cheaply before. And so I, I think investors would do well to think of it like that, which is just, it's very simple. So what are the input costs? What is the particular productivity like? Are we more or less productive and efficient than we were, you know, four years ago?
And so it's, it's no wonder that we're having this type of inflation. And then you overlay that, of course, with the, the money supply growth and, and the flexible letters that we use to try to, to deal with this.
And so I think that's, that's the environment that we're navigating, which is, we know we're dealing with currency debasement, but then we're also dealing with real world physical limits on productivity and, and input CAPX that a lot of those are solvable, but they take time.
That's, that's so well said. It's not, it's not too long ago. Probably was, it was just a few days ago, I said to my wife before we're going to bed, not to put it to sleep. But I, I did tell her that, you know, in 10 years, people would be reading about now, like with all the things that's going to happen. The, the financial history books are being being rewritten right now.
But anyway, Lynn, thank you as, as always, it's, it's always so much fun having you on, on the show. I'm sure the audience would like to connect with you.
不管怎样,琳恩,非常感谢你,一如既往地,每次你参加节目都非常有趣。我相信观众会很喜欢与你联系。
Where can I learn more about you and please also give a plug for your wonderful blog.
我在哪里可以了解更多关于你的信息,请也为你的精彩博客做个推荐。
I appreciate that. See, I've been making fun of my work at lindaldon.com. I'm also on Twitter at lindaldoncontact. And so I've read a free material and content that people can explore.
Fantastic. Lynn, thank you so much for taking time out of your busy schedule to speak with us here today.
太棒了!Lynn,非常感谢您抽出宝贵时间与我们今天在这里交谈。
Yep. Thanks for having me.
是的,谢谢你邀请我来。
But you can make an impact and the impact that you make will change your life. People will appreciate you to extend that you will not understand. When you save a life and you look that person interface, the amount of emotion that will go through you will amaze you.