Hello my friends today is June 10th. My name is Joseph and this is Markets Weekly. This week we're going to talk about three things. First we're going to talk about the prospect of the Fed raising their inflation target.
Secondly, we're going to talk about the surprise rate hikes from the Reserve Bank of Australia and the Bank of Canada. And lastly, we're going to talk about the prospect of us being in a new bull market.
Okay, starting with the Fed. Now over the past two months, there's been a lot of buzz in the press, about the prospect of global central banks raising their inflation target. Madame Lagarde from the ECB for example, has adjusted that the ECB could raise their inflation target, but only after they get inflation back to their current 2% target.
I think that there's a lot of buzz on central banks potentially raising their inflation target is because inflation is way above their target and they might not be able to get it under control without causing unemployment to spike a lot. Now this is such a debate that we also had in the 1970s.
Back in the 1970s, inflation was very high and the Fed chair at the time, Arthur Burns, was hiking rates to try to get inflation under control. When he was doing that, a lot of people in Congress and in the press were complaining.
Arthur Burns, very mean person, heard in the economy and raising unemployment. So Arthur Burns was basically constrained. He was not able to tighten monetary policy as much as he would have liked. What we learned in the 1970s though, was that trade-off between inflation and unemployment doesn't necessarily hold in the medium term because at the end of the 1970s, we had high inflation and also high unemployment.
But anyway, people, as we know, don't necessarily learn from history. So we're back to that same debate today again. People don't want the central banks to raise rates a lot because they're afraid that unemployment would go higher. And one way to get central banks to not raise their interest rates a lot is to simply change their inflation target higher.
Now, if the Fed were to do that, how would they go about raising inflation target? Well, one way they would definitely not go about doing it is that they would definitely not show up at a press conference and then just tell everyone, hey guys, I've decided that my inflation rate target is going to be 3% instead of 2%.
That's definitely not going to happen because according to how central banks think about the world, that will be very destabilizing. So from the central banks perspective, central banks inflation target anchors inflation expectations, which in turn anchors actual inflation.
Now, that's not necessarily how the world actually works, but that's how they think about it. Now, part of this makes sense to me, but part of it doesn't. It totally makes sense to me that someone's expectations of future inflation impacts their current economic activity. For example, if I'm a corporation and I expect prices to be 10% higher next year, then when I'm setting prices for next year, I'm obviously going to raise my prices by 10%.
And if I do that, voila, you get inflation. Or if I'm a consumer and I expect prices to be 10% higher next year than today, then obviously I'm going to go and buy stuff today. And if everyone does this, then well, you get more demand and you get higher actual inflation.
So I do think there's a relationship between inflation expectations and actual inflation. What's not super clear though is whether a central banks inflation target impacts inflation expectations. Honestly, there are surveys that suggest most people have no idea what the Federal Reserve does. And if you look at their recent history, they're not that good at hitting their inflation target anyway.
But besides all that, the Fed thinks that their inflation target has a big impact on inflation expectations. So they can't just will in nearly and raise it suddenly. But a very clever way they could go about doing it was that instead of announcing a change in their inflation target, announced a shift to an inflation band.
And reporting from Pedro de Castile, who was a very good reporter on the Fed, suggests that there are discussions in the Fed suggesting that right now. An inflation band would be, say, instead of the Fed shooting for a 2% inflation target, they shoot for a target range of inflation between 1.5 to 2.5%. Now, this is basically the same as raising their inflation target.
Now, let me give you an example. Why? Now, suppose that inflation is 2.5%. If you have a 2% inflation target, well, 2.5% is above 2%. So obviously you have to do something, maybe raise interest rates. But if you have an inflation band, that is 1.5 to 2.5%, well, 2.5% falls within that band, so mission accomplished, I don't have to do anything.
So in effect, if we transition to an inflation band, that's very much like raising inflation target, but in a more low key way. In Pedro's article, he cited that by former Vice Chair Clarida thought that this wasn't a good idea we're looking into. And if former Vice Chair Clarida is thinking about this, then you can bet that there are definitely many important people in the Fed that are giving this a serious look. Now, suppose that we have a new inflation band, that's 1% to 3%. That may sound like nothing is changing because it's still centered around 2%, but it would, in effect, be raising the Fed's inflation target to 3% by saying that 3% inflation is acceptable. Now, we won't know the results of the Fed's review. So the Fed periodically reviews its monetary policy framework. I think the next review is due in a couple years, but if you're thinking that the Fed would update there, and inflation target, I think this is how they would go about doing it. We'll find out in a couple years.
Now, let's talk about our second topic, the surprise rate hikes from the Reserve Bank of Australia and the Bank of Canada. Now, just for some context, the RBA and the Bank of Canada, like the Fed, the Fed hyde interest rates aggressively beginning last year, but unlike the Fed, they paused for a bit to take a look and to see what impact their rate hikes were having. And we both came to the conclusion that the rate hikes didn't seem to be working as they expected them to, and so they hyde rates again last week. They both said very similar things, that inflation seems to be higher and more stubborn than we expected.
So the RBA in particular had a really interesting graph. So after the RBA hyde rates, Governor Lowe of the RBA gave a speech the following day discussing the logic behind the recent rate hike. Now, he noted a lot of things, but one thing that said out to me is that it seemed a big part of the decision was that the labor market remained very strong, driving high wage gains, but also driving high unit labor costs. Now, unit labor costs are different from wage gains because they take into account productivity.
So, for example, if you're a worker and you get a wage increase, yes, on the surface, it sounds like labor costs are going higher. But if that worker also produces more per hour, then labor costs are not increasing because even though you're paying them more, they're also producing more. So you have to take into their productivity and account as well. But what's happening in Australia is that wages are going higher, but productivity is not really going up. It's actually declining in some cases. So if you have higher wages and declining productivity, you get higher unit labor costs. And in the case of Australia, Governor Lowe shows a very compelling graph that there's a strong relationship in Australia between inflation and unit labor costs. So rising unit labor costs are for shadowing persistently high inflation. And that seems to be a big part in the decision to raise rates again. Their labor market remains very strong.
Moving to the Bank of Canada, after Canada gave their rate hike decision, Deputy Governor Baudry gave a speech that gave us a bit more context on why they hike rates again. Now, Governor Baudry noted that they hike rates and paused in January, thinking that everything was trending in the right direction. But to their surprise, though, inflation perked back up, services activity remained strong, and even interest rate sensitive sectors like goods purchases and housing seem to be rebounding. So in a word, it didn't seem to be working, and that surprised them, so they hiked rates again.
But what was super interesting about Deputy Governor Baudry's speech, and I encourage you to read it, I'll link it to it in the notes below, is that he seems to think that we might be in a fundamental regime change, a higher inflationary world that requires interest rates to say higher for longer. He notes things like de-globalization, increasing investment demand from climate transition stuff, and aging population as some of the factors that are driving, perhaps, structural inflation. And that might suggest that rates are going to say high for longer, that might suggest that we are in a very different world today than we were pre-2020. Now, he's not the only central banker who has mentioned this before, other central bankers across the world have as well, and so that may inform our outlook for how other major central banks will have to behave in the coming months.
Now, lastly, let's talk about the idea of whether or not we're in a new bull market. So stocks have risen about 20% from their lows, and many people are thinking that we are in a new bull market. Indeed, I think the cover of Beren's magazine suggests that things are great, you guys should buy stocks, everything's okay, and if you look at stock prices over the past few weeks, they seem to go up every single day. Now, my personal opinion is that we are definitely not in a new bull market, and what I'm seeing in the market is very concerning.
So, when I look at asset prices, I like to look at it from the perspective of the stance of monetary policy. What I've learned over the past decade is that the biggest and most influential force in the markets are the global central banks, especially the Fed. And the global central banks, they are telling you that they want to stay higher for longer, they want to tight monetary policy, they're not done yet. And, you know, a lot of their tightening is potentially not yet to be felt, so there's often a lag between when monetary policy tight ends and when it's been felt in the economy. Now, I don't know what that lag is, but I'm getting the sense that it's probably not fully felt since we hike rates so rapidly. So, in the coming months, we might have more rate hikes from the Fed, we know we have quantitative tightening ongoing, we know there's a lot of issuance of shoulder securities that are probably going to put upward pressure on interest rates, and we also know that the economy is slowing.
So, I don't actually think these are the good ingredients for a new bull market. In my perspective, new bull markets would start once I think the Fed is ready to start easing again. There's a lot of people in the markets who have been placing pretty aggressive bets over the past few months that, you know, the Fed is on the cusp of cutting rates, on the cusp of ending the rate height and cycle. That's actually gone out of the short term interest rate markets, but I think the equity markets are a bit slow to realize that the rest of the market is more in step with the Fed for a higher, for longer stance. So, I don't think we're in a new bull market, I'm very, very cautious of what I see right now, and I suspect that I don't believe we're going to, we're in any risk of a crash or anything like that, but I do think that it warrants caution when everyone is thinking that we're in a new bull market and when stocks only go up, that's a recipe for disaster.
Okay, so that's all I prepared for today. If you like what I'm producing, please remember to like and subscribe. And of course, if you're interested in learning more about the markets, check out my free online courses at centralmaine101.com. And this week is an FOMC week, so I'll be back Wednesday to give you my thoughts on what happened at the Fed meeting. Thanks so much for tuning in, talk to you guys soon.